Professorspeak
Academic Papers in Plain English
Monday, June 29, 2020
Avoiding Another Recession
Thursday, June 25, 2020
Models of Economic Growth in the Post-recession Era
Wednesday, June 17, 2020
Whither the White Voter?
Thursday, June 11, 2020
Blowing the Whistle in the New Age of Big Data
Tuesday, June 9, 2020
Parking in Mexico City
Wednesday, June 3, 2020
Government Wages and Racial Pay Parity
Friday, May 29, 2020
The Brave New World of 21st-Century Capitalism
Google. Facebook. Amazon.
These so-called platform firms are big companies that are a huge part of our everyday lives.
But are they just like the major companies of the past? Or do they represent a new kind of business altogether?
A recent article in Politics & Society says that they are indeed a different kind of company. And whereas most studies attribute the differences to developments in markets and technology, the article in Politics & Society emphasizes instead political reasons.
The article is by K. Sabeel Rahman, associate professor of law at the Brooklyn Law School, and Kathleen Thelen, Ford Professor of Political Science at MIT.
Professor Rahman and Thelen begin by tracing the changing nature of large companies in the United States.
After World War II, the dominant model was the so-called Fordist model, as in the Ford Motor Company. Companies like Ford employed huge numbers of people. They offered benefits and permanent contracts to their employees. Fordist companies were interested in stable, long-term growth. And all stakeholders—ownership, management, labor—were seen as equal partners in a common endeavor.
Beginning in the 1980s, the Fordist model broke down with the rise in globalization. Unlike the old Fordist companies, the new breed of company relied not on employees but on a vast network of outsourced labor. Rather than stable, long-term growth, its main concerns were its daily stock price and its quarterly profits.
Today, platform firms like Google and Amazon represent yet another kind of model. Professors Rahman and Thelen say that this model differs in three ways.
First, investors are in it for the long haul. Second, the goal is not stable, long-term growth or quarterly targets but market dominance. And third, platform firms enjoy a direct link to their users that companies of the past never did. How many times have you visited Amazon or Google or Facebook today?
This brings us to the distinguishing feature of the article: its emphasis on the political factors behind the rise of this new kind of firm. Professor Rahman and Thelen identify three.
The first is the regulatory environment or rather the lack thereof. When platform firms burst onto the scene, the existing business regulations were holdovers from a very different kind of economy, one dominated by manufacturing. Those regulations were totally unsuited to the regulatory needs that arose in the wake of the new firms.
The second reason why platform firms have become so big concerns antitrust law. Antitrust law in the United States is today largely interpreted in terms of consumer welfare. What matters is not the size of a firm but its affect on prices. If a merger will result in lower prices for consumers, then, hey, it must be a good thing, right?
That brings us to the third and final reason behind the growth of platform firms, and that is the astronomical growth of the financial sector. There’s simply a lot of investment capital available, and a lot of that capital has been poured into platform firms.
Where, then, does this leave us?
It certainly leaves workers in a precarious position. In the 1980s and 1990s such companies as Kodak and Nike became well known for outsourcing their labor, replacing relatively expensive US workers with cheap workers overseas. The platform firms have only continued that trend by relying on a large pool of independent contractors who have no job security and receive no benefits. Professors Rahman and Thelen end their article by suggesting reforms that would strengthen the position of workers, including making it easier for workers to organize, promoting consumer-producer coalitions, and reinterpreting antitrust laws to focus on size and not just consumer prices.
Monday, May 25, 2020
The Long-View History of Sanctuary Cities
Thursday, May 21, 2020
Minimum Wages in Indonesia
Monday, May 18, 2020
Forest Protection in Argentina
Tuesday, May 12, 2020
Resistance during the Chinese Famine, 1959–61
Friday, May 8, 2020
Inequality a Major Theme in Latest Issue of Politics & Society
Tuesday, May 5, 2020
Property Rights in Medieval Egypt
In Egypt back then, there was a group of people known as the mamluks. Mamluks were both soldiers and slaves. They were not native Egyptians but were purchased in slave markets in Europe and brought to Egypt as children. Trained to fight, these slave-soldiers served Egypt's leaders as a military elite.
In time, the mamluks overthrew their masters and created their own sultanate—their own autocratic state. That was in 1250.
The mamluks suddenly controlled much of Egypt's arable land--and found themselves confronting a property rights question: Who should have rights to the land they controlled, and in what form? They decided to administer the land as a collective, granting temporary rights to pieces of land to individual mamluks in exchange for services to the state.
The mamluks, though, lived by certain rules, one of which undermined their ability to retain their land as a collective: mamluk status—and hence access to the collectively owned land—could not be passed down to one's sons. That was, as they say, a design flaw. Why? Well, most mamluks wanted to provide for their male descendants. One way to do that was to secure for them a piece of land—land that was privately owned and would remain in the family. So, individual mamluks began making deals with the sultan, deals that allowed them to slowly build wealth. Eventually, they built enough wealth to convert what had been temporary rights to land into permanent rights.
The most popular means of securing land for one's sons was to transform the land into a religious endowment, or waqf. Descendants of a mamluk who founded a waqf could be named a custodian of the waqf and enjoy the benefits thereof. But regardless of the means, little by little, the land that was owned collectively by the sultanate passed into other hands. By 1517, the mamluk sultanate no longer owned enough land to support itself and came to an end.
This account of the mamluks is found in an article by Lisa Blaydes, a professor of political science at Stanford University. The article appears in the September 2019 issue of Politics & Society. As Professor Blaydes points out, scholars have paid little attention to the development of property rights in non-European parts of the world. Her analysis of the mamluks of medieval Egypt complements European-centered studies, thereby opening up new new points of comparison and new ways to understand how autocratic regimes manage—or perhaps mismanage—their institutions.